| |
|
ELEMENTS THAT CHARACTERISE AN EFFICIENT AND
EFFECTIVE LAND MARKET
|
The Policy and Regulatory Framework
|
Market Assessment (Participants, Goods and Services, and Financial Instruments)
|
Pillar 1 - Land Registration and Cadastre
|
Pillar 2 - Valuation
|
Pillar 3 - Financial Services
Table 2. Scoring for the land market indicators of Table 1. |
Score |
Criteria |
0 |
There is no evidence at all that this matter is being addressed. |
1 |
There is minimal evidence that the stated feature is present, but it is not clear that the requested functionality is provided. |
2 |
There are some major problems, the system cannot be said to work adequately, but the basic components are in place or being developed. |
3 |
The functionality is basically provided. There are some known problems, but things basically work. |
4 |
The system works smoothly and could be considered consistent with what one would find in another market economy. |
5 |
The feature or functionality offer performance levels consistent with that required for EU membership and with what one would expect in an EU member state. |
The detailed case studies carried out as part of the ACE project enabled the study team to assign scores for each of the indicators of Table 1 for each of the six study countries. Although the numerical values are obtained from qualitative assessments and are therefore not rigorously derived, they should be consistent and provide a means of measuring a country’s progress in comparison with other countries.
The scores were then used to prepare a Land Policy Framework Matrix (Table 3) that was used to summarise the key issues that arise during the reform process and to give a visual check on progress. The Matrix illustrates the overall progress that is needed in the reform of each of the land market sectors (land registration, valuation, financial services, market activity and land policy). The results for each of the six study countries are given in Appendix B. These tables
The countries are progressing through four phases, starting with a command economy, moving through a transition period into a market driven economy with the final intention of reaching the status of the leading members of the European Union. Thus a score greater than 1.5 shows that the transition process has begun while a score greater than 3 shows that the land market is becoming active. A score in excess of 4 would suggest that a level has been reached that equates with that in the EU.
While the earlier analysis indicates the state of development of the land market in the reform process, it takes little account of the actual performance as measured in terms of how active the market has become. Empirical evidence suggests that there is a direct correlation between progress in the transition towards the market economy and the level of market activity although as discussed earlier the performance is much stronger in urban rather than in rural areas. Table 4 identifies performance indicators that may be used to assess the market activity. The performance indicators are compared with EU norms, obtained from examining the statistics of five EU countries - Denmark, Finland, Netherlands, Sweden and the UK (reported in the Land Administration Inventory of Europe, Part 2 published on behalf of MOLA by the UK Land Registry).
Table 3. Land Policy Framework Matrix
LAND POLICY FRAMEWORK MATRIX for (Country) |
|||||||
COMMAND ECONOMY ------->I<-----------TRANSITION ECONOMY--------------->I<------MARKET ECONOMY-------> |----- EU------ |
|||||||
LMI score |
<1.5 |
1.5-1.90 |
2.0-2.4 |
2.5-2.9 |
3.0-3.4 |
3.5-3.9 |
>4.0 |
Policy Level Framework |
Government does not support land market development or individual property rights |
Weak political support for objectives of land market. No broad political consensus. |
Inconsistent or inadequate policies leading to fragmented land management. |
Individual policies sound. Some policy difficulties with coordination & information exchange. |
Policies are coherent and preparations have started for EU accession. |
All reforms are complete and negotiations for accession are under way. |
Clearly defined and integrated land policies that comply with EU regulations. |
Market Assessment – Participants |
Relationship between land and people is weak with focus on use rights and occupancy, not ownership. Strong informal sector. Poor information |
Participation severely restricted with unclear ownership rights and outstanding legal claims. Identification of owners and parcels difficult |
Participation starting but interest limited due to structural problems and lack of market confidence. Data flows are weak. |
Relationship between land and people becoming clear. Growing interest in land as a market commodity. Data flows improving. |
Strong connection between land and people with a range of participants and types of land for sale. Information flows are working. |
Institutional investors and investment funds are active in the market. Risks in real estate investment seen as low. Information is transparent |
Large range of participants, goods and services. Real estate seen as a good, safe long-term investment. |
Pillar One – Land Registration and Cadastre |
Registration not legally required. Insecure laws with respect to ownership, inheritance and disposal of rights. Weak regulating authorities. |
Registration is legally required but there are inconsistent laws and confusion over administrative responsibility between agencies. |
Compilation of registers and land reform under way. Institutional arrangements and land law need to be strengthened. Poor title information. |
Requirements for land title registration are basically satisfactory but delays in transactions occur due to technical and organisation problems. |
Land Registration System is basically working Problems with titling are mainly in large cities and in areas under land reform. |
Records near completion. System working efficiently (except in capital cities). Titles are secure. Land reform is complete. |
System is efficient and supports secondary market services, significant private sector involvement & cost recovery. |
Pillar Two - Valuation |
Absence of any accepted methodology for market based valuations. No body tasked with valuation. |
There is a valuation methodology but little up to date or reliable data. Valuation may not be connected to market price. |
Valuations tied to market price but results are unreliable due to poor data, low level of transactions, and poor reporting. |
Systematic valuation records being compiled. Valuation seen as necessary to support the land market. Real Estate prices volatile. |
Valuation system able to support market based property tax. Regulatory procedures are in place to monitor data quality . |
Secure, reliable system supporting land transactions and fair and efficient property tax collection. |
Complete valuation data sets available that can link to other land administration records. Significant private sector involvement. |
Pillar Three -Financial Services |
Almost complete absence of financing mechanisms. |
Cash sales take place but the market is volatile with few transactions and potential speculation. |
Mortgage support being introduced but foreign investment into real estate may be restricted. |
Mortgages have become more accepted, and development financing is emerging. |
Mortgages more widely available, interest rates near to EU/G7 norm . |
Macro-economic stability helps real estate investment, encouraging institutional investors. |
Pension funds, investment funds, life assurance and major investors are in place and safe |
General Assessment |
Land market operates through informal sector outside government authority. |
Severe strategic impediments to land market activity with reforms progressing very slowly. |
Major impediments to a formal land market. Reforms in progress but there are major policy weaknesses. |
Reforms are being implemented but with unresolved difficulties that inhibit development. |
System is basically working and land rights are seen as secure and transferable. |
A mature market is beginning to appear with transparent land dealings. |
Stable and secure real estate market, secondary market services developed. |
Table 4. Land Market Performance Indicators
Land Market Performance Indicator |
Calculation method for CEC country |
Expected figures for EU member |
|
1 |
How complete is the land regularisation/restitution process? (2) |
CEC1 = Total number of properties settled |
EU1 = 100% |
2 |
How complete is the land title database? |
CEC2 = Total number of loaded titles |
EU2 =100% |
3 |
What is the level of annual queries of the land title database? |
CEC3 = Total number of annual enquiries |
EU3 =60% |
4 |
What is the level of annual transfers of title? |
CEC4 = Total number of annual transfers |
EU4 = 7% |
5 |
What is the level of annual issue of mortgages? |
CEC5 = Total number of new mortgages per year |
EU5 = 9% |
Land Market Performance Indicator = (CEC1/EU1+CEC2/EU2+CEC3/EU3+CEC4/EU4+CEC5/EU5 ) * 100 |
100% |
Based on the definitions contained in Table 4, a Land Market Performance Indicator of 100% would indicate a land market reaching the same level of market activity as that which may be found within one of the more advanced EU member states. The Performance Indicator is defined in such a way that it reflects the availability of land that has clear title, with no regulatory impediments for sale, as well as the general market activity that includes enquiries, sales and mortgages. It is possible to develop this further and to include indicators based on area, land value and number of new constructions although this was not done in the present study.
The overall Land Market Model has two distinct measurement domains
A plot of the Land Market Indicator against the Performance Indicator should produce a diagram like that in Figure 2 (overleaf). A Performance Indicator of the order of 90-100% (Table 4) and a Land Market Indicator of 4.5 or 5 (Table 1 & 2) corresponds to the land market status in most developed EU states, while scores of <20% and <1.5 correspond to a closed command economy. In improving land markets the aim would be to increase both the market activity and the market reform, thus increasing the Land Market Indicator and the Performance Indicator towards their maximum values. The case studies suggest that the market has three phases of development:
The Land Market requires a certain amount of reform from its pre-1989 position before it can significantly develop. There must be a critical mass of property with clear title, secure boundaries and disposition rights. The legal basis must support private property, the regulating institutions must be in place and there must be a critical mass of participants with access to suitable funding. This implies that this phase is dominated by initial legal, institutional and regulatory reforms. There will only be a slow increase in market activity, linked to improvements in the technical infrastructure, once the initial conditions have been established. As the reforms become more substantial, the access to disposable property and the amount of available property becomes clearer, the regulating institutions begin to work, the financial institutions develop and the risks are seen to reduce resulting in increased market activity.
The Land Market now has most of the institutions in place and they are functioning. The data quality is good and the regulating institutions are sound. The credit facilities are available. The market becomes open to a wider range of participants and it is the dynamic energy of these that drives the development. Significant increases in market activity take place for relatively little improvement in the institutional reform position. Land prices will rise significantly during this process and wealth creation is achieved.
The market is beginning to saturate as it approaches the levels consistent with market economies and the EU member states. In order to finally reach the EU levels, there is a further reform (or harmonisation) of laws and regulations that are required. These are more concerned with environment and the creation of instruments to implement EU policies such as the CAP (Common Agricultural Policy). Market activities will not be suddenly stimulated during this period unless significant distortions are introduced externally (e.g. the agricultural land market is suddenly liberalised overnight).
Figure 2. Land Market Indicator and Performance Indicator
Figure 3 shows the development of a Transition Curve, which can be expected to represent the path of a transition country as it experiences the different phases and identifies the dominant forces during the transition from the command to market economy.
Figure 3. The Transition Curve
The theoretical analysis outlined in §2 above was developed through the gathering of data and a series of workshops in which various ideas and components of the model were discussed. The model was then tested and scores evaluated both by members of the research team and by representatives of the six countries concerned - the Czech Republic (CZ), Hungary (HU), Latvia (LA), Poland (PL), Slovakia (SK) and Slovenia (SI). The elements identified in Table 1 were quantified on the basis of the criteria that are given in Table 2. The results are given in Table 5 based on data gathered in 1997 since when the markets have continued to progress.
A summary of Table 5 is provided in Table 6. In general, as can be seen from Tables 5 and 6, the market reforms have progressed fastest in the land registration and cadastral pillar and less quickly in pillars two (valuation) and three (financial services). The reforms in pillar one have received significant support from organisations such as EU PHARE and the World Bank and have enabled the land restitution and compensation programmes to be largely completed. This has been both a political priority and an economic necessity in satisfying the aspirations of the former landowners, and reducing the role of the state as the principal landowner and land manager.
The development of the valuation pillar has been more slow. The reasons for this are related to the lack of a historical role for property valuers and the lack of a central agency or institution charged with responsibility in this area. In addition, the relatively small number of commercial transactions during the early reform years and the lack of property taxes in most countries in the region have also caused progress to be slow. There is also a significant lack of information and expertise concerning valuation which has historically been concerned more with productivity than with monetary value. The financial services are mostly provided by the private sector, so naturally this pillar will only strengthen as the market deepens and there is an increased demand for financial products and services. Necessary precursors for this include mortgage laws to protect the interests of the various parties and clear, strong foreclosure and bankruptcy laws to lessen the risk of debtors defaulting and creditors being unable to obtain re-possession or adequate compensation. The generally higher level of interest rates in these countries also restricts demand.
Table 5. Land Market Indicator scoring for the six study countries
Elements of the Land Market Model |
CZ |
HU |
LA |
PL |
SK |
SI |
|||||||
The Policy and Regulatory Framework
Average |
1 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
4 |
|||||||
Market Assessment
Average |
3 |
4 |
3 |
3 |
3 |
3 |
|||||||
Pillar 1 - Land Registration and Cadastre Average |
4 |
4 |
3 |
4 |
3 |
4 |
|||||||
Pillar 2 – Valuation Average |
2 |
2 |
2 |
2 |
2 |
2 |
|||||||
Pillar 3 – Financial Services Average |
4 |
4 |
3 |
3 |
4 |
4 |
Table 6. Overall Assessment of the Land Market Indicators
Sector of Land Market |
CZ |
HU |
LV |
PL |
SK |
SI |
Mean |
Policy Framework |
2.5 |
2.9 |
2.0 |
2.2 |
2.2 |
2.9 |
2.5 |
Market Assessment |
2.2 |
2.9 |
2.4 |
2.6 |
2.0 |
2.2 |
2.4 |
Pillar 1 - Land Registration |
3.5 |
3.7 |
3.2 |
2.8 |
2.8 |
3.0 |
3.2 |
Pillar 2 – Valuation |
2.2 |
2.6 |
2.0 |
2.4 |
2.0 |
2.0 |
2.2 |
Pillar 3 – Finance |
2.2 |
2.9 |
2.2 |
2.2 |
2.2 |
2.2 |
2.3 |
Overall Assessment |
2.5 |
3.0 |
2.4 |
2.5 |
2.2 |
2.5 |
2.5 |
The Policy Framework supports all these activities. Governments must adopt clear policies and priorities and provide a sound organisational structure. There are often conflicts between Ministries concerning their respective areas of interest and this will influence the policy framework. The governments have had to develop transition policies for all sectors of the economy and it can be difficult to prioritise the aim of developing land markets in competition with other sectors.
Land Policy Framework Matrices were produced for each country studied and provided a profile of the overall reform identifying the major impediments at the time (see Annex B). The land market performance indicators described in Table 4 were calculated for the six study countries, based on information gathered during the case study, and the results are shown in Table 7.
Table 7. Land Market performance indicators for the six countries
Performance Indicator |
CZ |
HU |
LV |
PL |
SK |
SI |
EU norm |
|
1 |
How complete is the land regularisation/restitution process? |
60? |
95? |
50? |
75? |
30 |
90? |
100 |
2 |
How complete is the land title database? |
90? |
80? |
30? |
50 |
30? |
0 |
100 |
3 |
What is the level of annual queries of the land title database? |
10? |
15? |
5? |
10? |
10 |
10 |
60 |
4 |
What is the level of annual transfers of title? |
1? |
2.5? |
1? |
1? |
1? |
1? |
7 |
5 |
What is the level of annual issue of mortgages? |
0.1? |
0.2? |
0.05? |
0.05? |
0.1? |
0.1 |
9 |
Overall assessment (rounded to nearest 5%) |
35 |
45 |
20 |
30 |
20 |
25 |
100 |
When applied to Figure 3 the position of each country on he transition curve becomes apparent, as shown in Figure 4.
Figure 4. Transitional Curve for the case study countries
In making recommendations, the study team made certain assumptions, namely:
The recommendations are presented as actions for governments to undertake. The emphasis is on encouraging governments to put in place the right base conditions and supporting framework to allow the land market to develop. Governments must of course be wary of over–regulation, yet must provide enough support to ensure that the regulatory measures are soundly implemented. Inevitably, whatever policies are adopted, they represent a compromise between the interests of the different parties, and what the government perceives as its political priorities. In particular:
The policy recommendations that follow concentrate on those aspects that will bring real sustainable benefits in the development and nurture of land markets. It is not the intention to make specific recommendations for the individual case study countries, as each has its own specific set of circumstances. Instead, some general policy level recommendations are presented that appear to apply to all transition countries. These relate to:
Background
The relationship between the ownership and use of land and property was broken or suppressed during the socialist era, limiting the citizen’s powers of disposal with, in some cases, the land itself being expropriated. Large socialist agricultural enterprises and co-operatives were created and in many cases, the evidence of the earlier field boundaries was destroyed. In some countries, the land ownership records were not updated, even in the case of inheritance. As a consequence, the relationship between people and property became uncertain.
Land restitution programmes have addressed the issue of expropriated property. In the case of eligible claimants in the central and eastern European countries (3), the programmes of restitution are largely complete though in some countries the problems of boundaries have not yet been addressed. In several central and eastern European countries there are still substantial inconsistencies or inadequacies in the completion of the land registers owing to the "missing parcels" and "missing owners" resulting from the socialisation of agriculture. The market mechanisms cannot work until the basic state directed reassignment of property relationships is complete and the records show a position that accords with reality. This does not mean that the old boundaries must be marked out in the field, but it does mean regularising the new and old records in order that people can have clear title and also can see where the properties are located. This will mark the completion of the state intervention into the rearrangement of land ownership relations
Recommendation 1 - Completion of the Transition Process It should be a policy objective of the government to complete the transition process in the land sector and establish the base conditions for market forces. This must include regularisation of all titles and ownership relations and the settlement of any likely future claims as a prerequisite for completing the process of economic transition. |
Actions Required
Success Indicators
Potential Impediments
Background
The establishment and operation of land administration systems and functioning land markets involves substantial co-operation between several different sectors of government. The transition countries are characterised by a lack of institutional co-operation and an absence of "ownership" of land issues that can lead to politics operating in a vacuum. There is a real danger that wider issues become lost and specific issues are addressed only within the narrower confines of a single ministerial brief. There are also dangers that policies in one sector will significantly impact on policies or ongoing programmes in other sectors, thus creating confusion and waste.
The state has potentially conflicting roles as landowner, as land administrator and regulator, and as creator of measures in support of land market development. There needs to be a coherent and integrated approach. The land market requires a clear national land policy that is implemented within a legal and regulatory environment that is certain, with government policies that are not subject to sudden change. All too often there is a lack of a high level integrated policy in land matters and little formal mechanism for inter-ministerial debate on land matters.
Recommendation 2 – The establishment of a coherent national land policy Governments should develop an integrated national land policy, including the identification and provision of the necessary supporting means and instruments that will allow high level political debate and the obtaining of broad inter-Ministerial support. The creation of a coherent integrated strategy for dealing in land and property should be a priority for both urban and rural land. |
Actions Required
Success Indicators
Potential Impediments
Background
The overriding political objective within the six central and eastern European countries is EU accession and four of these (Poland, Czech Republic, Hungary and Slovenia) have already been accepted for entry under the next round of enlargement. The EU has opened negotiations with all 11 applicant countries. The basic principles for enlargement were laid out at the 1993 Copenhagen European Council and the acquis communautaire is accepted as the definitive guide to the collective legislation that must be adopted in order to harmonise and be able to assume the obligations of membership. The Commission published its Opinion on the applicants ability to adopt the acquis in July 1997 and the basic assessment is that the countries are moving towards compliance.
From a land administration perspective, there is a fundamental difficulty in that land is not specifically addressed in the acquis. In order to enter the Union, the applicant country must have a functioning market economy, a prerequisite for which is the possession of an accepted method of registering private property. In all previous enlargements the applicant countries already possessed such institutions. Land received no special attention, other than in the creation of an awareness of the need to address the broader objectives of the single market and to open up the land market to competitive forces from anywhere in the Union.
Unlike many other traded goods, the supply of land is strictly limited. The effect of an open land market policy on the transition states is potentially damaging as most of the transition countries have significantly lower agricultural land prices (one tenth, on average) than EU member states. As a result, large parts of the countryside could very quickly become foreign owned. This would be politically destabilising and socially disruptive and would outweigh any gains in productivity that the new investment would bring.
Recommendation 3 - EU Accession and land ownership It should be a policy objective of the applicant government to negotiate a transition period for the full liberalisation of the agricultural land market. Given the start of the accession negotiations in 1998 and the planned accession in the next few years, these issues are of extreme importance at the present time. The urban land markets should be fully liberalised immediately. |
Actions Required
Success Indicators
Potential Impediments
Background
The state is responsible for the legal and regulatory framework within which the land markets operate. The state also needs an efficient land administration capability in order to meet other national policy objectives, including justice and home affairs, revenue generation through tax policies, environmental controls, rural development, cross border issues and municipal administration. The impending EU membership places additional demands upon the land administration, especially in the adoption of the Common Agricultural Policy (CAP) and the implementation measures that include the Integrated Agricultural Control System (IACS). The socialist legacy of incomplete land records and uncertainty in title (including technical defects) need to be corrected.
The land administration functions established in the transition economies have concentrated on the re-establishment of the necessary legal framework, the establishment of a services network and the registration of title to land and property, as well as the support for the property restitution and compensation (and similar) programmes. In some cases it is recognised that the institutional arrangements may not be optimal for efficient land administration and in other areas it is clear that the institutions face significant problems in introducing modern technology (and especially large-scale national information systems).
Additional demands will be imposed by the IACS. It is recognised that the information flows are currently weak and the processing time for transfers is too long in all of the capital cities. There are known difficulties in the legal definition of land and buildings and in the trading of use rights including leases. Most countries have inadequate valuation systems, while the financial sectors of some countries need legal support in dealing with mortgages, bankruptcy and foreclosures. These matters are all concerned with strengthening the legal framework and the regulatory authorities, and improving the performance of the relevant institutions. Private sector involvement is almost completely restricted to contracts for routine technical activities (such as mapping).
Recommendation 4 – Land Administration – Institution Building There needs to be institutional strengthening of the land administration sector, which includes the three pillars of the regulatory authorities (registration, valuation, real estate financing) and the underlying legal framework. There is also a need to establish the technical systems needed to implement and provide a national level of service within a reasonable time and with a high level of security and confidence. |
Actions Required
Success Indicators
Potential Impediments
Background
The land markets in central and eastern Europe operate under many disincentives including punitive transfer taxes and notarial fees, the lack of credit financing, inadequate valuation methods and a poor risk assessment of the market. Other disincentives arise as a result of the restitution of land parcels that were created more than 50 years ago, resulting is fields whose size, shape and location are incompatible with modern agricultural practice. There is weakness in the availability of market based information including real valuations and market prices while the mechanism for connecting buyers and sellers is underdeveloped. Agricultural support is an important aspect of rural development, yet it is not prioritised in some countries. Urban land markets are seen as subject to severe technical and legal delays in effecting transfers and there are serious weaknesses in the mortgage laws of some countries.
The emergence of significant private investments driving insurance funds, building societies, savings and loan organisations or mortgage banks has not yet happened. Institutional investors are still noticeably absent compared to EU countries and property (especially agricultural) is not perceived as a safe long-term investment.
There are severe weaknesses in the land market that can be addressed through support measures aimed at creating the right environment for bottom up processes to be initiated by individual owners or groups of owners. This needs to be addressed not through direct state intervention, but by the identification and removal of obstacles that discourage the formation of viable agricultural units or act as a disincentive to the urban property market.
This includes the removal of high transaction costs (notarial fees and some of the higher registration fees), the removal of entry barriers (parcels without adequate documentation) and establishing incentives for voluntary consolidation (waiver of transfer tax, etc.) and increasing the access to credit. Support can include measures aimed at improving the quality and availability of the goods (i.e. the land units) and also supporting the entry of a wider range of participants into the market.
Recommendation 5 - Land Market Support Measures There needs to be a declared policy objective of liberalising the agricultural and urban land markets through creating more open competition, providing support for information flows and removing entry barriers and disincentives. In addition it is necessary to provide incentives for voluntary land consolidation. |
Actions Required
Success Indicators
Potential Impediments
A number of key policy issues were identified as part of the study, especially relating to:
Traditionally, the approach has been to put in place the legal framework, then identify the necessary technical matters to carry out the mandated tasks. Given the close connection between the performance of this state sector and the impact on declared cabinet level policy, land administration authorities cannot adopt a purely technical viewpoint and must consider the wider costs and benefits. Cabinet level policy needs to address the market transition, open and transparent markets, EU membership, the creation of a viable agricultural sector, efficiency in the administration and the promotion of the private sector.
A number of policy level recommendations are put forward in section 4 which are aimed at assisting with the development of effective and efficient land markets. The recommendations are not aimed at a particular study country, but identify and address common problem areas that were identified during the study.
There are specific issues that need further study
- Land ownership;
- Valuation and taxation of land and construction;
- Control and management of land use ;
- Development control;
- Land related information;
- Agricultural policy.
In conclusion, this paper wishes to emphasise land policy. The land policy needs to be a response to the declared government aims. It should involve active participation and discussion with all operators in the land sector including other government agencies, the regulating forces and the market participants. The introduction of the financing and valuation sectors that underpin the trade in goods and services heralds the transition to the market economy and completes the three regulatory pillars. Achieving a balance between the regulatory structures and the market forces will allow controlled growth and will be perceived as of general economic and social well being to the populace.
(1) Source: Agricultural Property Agency of the State Treasury, Poland
(2) This figure must take into account all matters connected with the full and correct registration of title (or deed) and full description of parcel data, i.e. it includes the completion or correction of problems such as restitution, compensation, missing property boundaries, missing owners and all matters which detract from the completion
(3) But note that there are still unsatisfied demands from former Polish and Sudetenland ethnic Germans, with claims on Polish, Czech and Slovak territory, and uncertainty in the position of non-citizens with permanent resident status in the Baltic countries.
ACE, 1998, The Development of Land Markets in central and eastern Europe, Final Report Project P2128R, 121 pages, ACE programme, EC Brussels (unpublished).
Brooks, K., Guasch, J.L., Bravermna, A., Csaki, Cs., Agriculture and the transition to the Market. Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol 5 No 4.
DTZ 1997, European Commercial Property Markets Overview, 27 pages.
EBRD 1994. Measuring Transition: Extracts from the Transition Report, 1994. Economic Transition in eastern Europe and the former Soviet Union. EBRD. UK. 27 pages.
Euroconsult, 1995. Farm Restructuring and Land Tenure in Reforming Socialist Economies: a comparative analysis of eastern and central Europe. World Bank Discussion paper 268. The World Bank, Washington 147 pages.
Euroforum, 1997. Mortgages and Property Finance in Poland, Hungary and the Czech Republic. Proceedings of 2 day conference, 27/28th May Budapest Hilton 2nd Annual Conference. Euroforum. London.
Euroforum, 1998. Mortgages and Property Finance in Poland, Hungary and the Czech Republic. Proceedings of 2 day conference, 31st March / 1st April Sheraton Hotel Warsaw. 3rd Annual Conference. Euroforum. London.
Gelb, A., and Gray, C., 1991. The transformation of economies in central and eastern Europe, Policy, Research and External Affairs. World Bank, Washington. No 17. 74 pages.
FIG Publication. 1995. Statement on the Cadastre. FIG Bureau. Australia.
Grossman, R.G., and Brussard, W., 1992. Agrarian Land Law in the Western World. CAB International. UK. 280 pages.
Lerman, Z., Brooks, K., and Csaki, Cs., 1994. Land Reform and Restructuring in Ukraine. World Bank Discussion Paper 270. World Bank, Washington. 101 pages.
OECD 1992. Urban Land Markets: Policies for the 1990’s. 149 pages.
OECD 1993. OECD Economic Surveys – Hungary. OECD Paris.
OECD 1994. OECD Economic Surveys – the Czech and Slovak Republics. OECD Paris.
Riddell, J, (Ed) 1997. Private and Public Sector Co-operation in National Land Tenure Development in central and eastern Europe. UN FAO. In Rivista Italiana di Telerilevamento No. 10 May 1997.
Schwarz, A., D’Andrea Tyson, L., 1992. Reprivatisation in Eastern Europe: roundtable report. In Reprivatisation in Central and Eastern Europe, Central and Eastern European Privatisation Network.
Swinnen, J.F. (Ed). 1997. Political Economy of Agrarian Reform in Central and Eastern Europe. Ashgate. UK. 397 pages.
UNECE 1996., Land Administration Guidelines: with special reference to countries in transition. UN ECE Geneva. ECE/HBP/96. 94 pages.
UNECE 1997a. Land Administration Inventory in Europe (Parts 1 & 2). UK HMLR
UNECE 1997b. Financing Land Administration projects in Countries in Transition. May 1997, Geneva.
UNECE 1997c. Workshop on Definition and Numbering of Objects in Cadastres and Land Registers. MOLA (Meeting of officials on Land Administration), Oslo, 16/17th June 1997.
UNCHS The Habitat II Land initiative: access to land and security of tenure as conditions for sustainable urban development. UNCHS Vol 3 No 2.
World Bank 1996. The 1997 Index of Economic Freedom, Transitions, Vol.7/11, pp. 22-24.
Zavadskas. E., Sloan. B., and Kaklauskus, A., 1997. Property Valuation and Investment in Central and Eastern Europe. Proceedings of the International Conference held in Vilnius, Lithuania, Vilnius Gediminas Technical University. 371pages.
This study was carried out with the financial support of the ACE programme. The study could not have been possible without the help, advice, encouragement and participation of a large number of people who have all kindly invested time and effort in the project. The principal list of contributors is contained below, however it does not include all the people who have taken part in the meetings, interviews, review stages or have been a source of much needed encouragement. The group would like to particularly thank Ruzenka Zimova, Jaroslav Vigner, Vaclav Slaboch and President J. Sima (Czech Republic), President I. Hornansky (Slovak Republic), Maria Toth, and Laszlo Niklasz (Hungary), Lars Lauridsen and Stig Enemark (Denmark), Elfriede Fendel (Netherlands) and Robin McLaren (Scotland).
This study was undertaken by a group of consultants and academics who are actively working in the land market sector of transition countries. The multidisciplinary approach involved professionals from the fields of land registration, economics and agriculture drawn from both the EU member states and the countries in transition. The principal collaborators included:
Dr R. Baldwin (UK). Project Coordinator. Dr Baldwin is a consultant who is active in the land registration and cadastre sector. He has spent six years working on land registration projects in Hungary, Czech Republic, Lebanon and shorter assignments in Slovenia and Slovakia and other countries. Currently he is the GIS/LIS Projects Director for Central and Eastern Europe, BlomInfo A/S.
Dr P. Bielek (Slovak Republic). Dr Bielek is Deputy Director of Research at the Soil Fertility Research Clinic, Bratislava, and is a specialist in soil quality assessment and agricultural planning and has published more than 140 papers.
Professor T. Bogaerts (Netherlands). Professor Bogaerts is Vice-Dean of the Faculty of Civil Engineering and Geosciences at the Delft University of Technology. He is a specialist in land registration and cadastral systems and has carried out numerous consultancy missions in the countries of central Europe including Poland, Czech Republic, Slovak Republic and Hungary and other countries on behalf of the EU Phare programme. He has published extensively.
Professor C. Csaki (Hungary). Professor Csaki is a World Bank Economist and former Rector of the Budapest University of Economic Science and has carried out numerous missions on behalf of the World Bank in Hungary, Moldova, Ukraine, Lithuania and Latvia. He is responsible for several of the World Bank Discussion papers in the agricultural reform sector and has published extensively.
Professor P. Dale (UK). Professor Dale is President of FIG and is based at University College London. He was the Chairman of the UN ECE Land Administration Guidelines Taskforce, and has carried out consultancy in central and eastern Europe and many other countries on behalf of the EU Phare programme and the World Bank. He is the author of several books and more than 100 papers.
Professor A. Hopfer. (Poland). Professor Hopfer is Deputy Rector of University of Agriculture and Technology at Olsztyn (UATO) and former Dean of Faculty of Surveying and Rural Land Management. He is an expert in surveying planning and management of rural land and the countryside, and cadastre and land information systems, real estate valuation and management. He has published more than 250 papers in Polish and foreign scientific periodicals, among them 20 books, and is a member of several international and national professional organisations.
Ms K. Kovacs (Hungary). Ms Kovacs is a member of the Department of Agricultural Economics at Budapest University of Agricultural Economics, specialising in real estate appraisal.
Dr B. Lipej (Slovenia). Dr Lipej is the Deputy Director of the cadastre authority in Slovenia and is a specialist in cadastral systems. She is the Vice Chairman of UN ECE MOLA and national co-ordinator of the UN FAO land valuation programme in Slovenia. She is a representative at FIG, CERCO, MEGRIN and other international groups and societies. She is the author of more than 150 articles and papers.
Professor G. Modos (Hungary). Professor Modos is a member of the Department of Agricultural Economics and is a specialist in agricultural restructuring and economics.
Dr G. Remetey-Fülöpp (Hungary). Dr Remetey is a Senior Counsellor in the Department of Lands and Mapping of the Ministry of Agriculture in Hungary and was a member of the UN ECE Task Force on Land Administration. He is active in CERCO, UN MOLA, FIG and other international societies and working groups on behalf of Hungary. He is the author of numerous scientific papers.
Mr V. Suchanek (Czech Republic). Mr Suchanek is the Director of Informatics within the Czech Office for Surveying, Mapping and Cadastre, and has special responsibility for the co-ordination of all foreign assistance projects contributing to reform and modernisation. He is the Director charged with responsibility for the development of the next generation automated land registration and cadastral system.
Dr A. Udovc (Slovenia). Dr Udovc is a member of the Biotechnical Faculty at the University of Ljubljana and is a specialist in farm and crop information systems and land valuation. He is active in UN FAO and World Bank projects in valuation and agricultural development.
Dr J. Valis (Slovak Republic). Dr Valis is Deputy Director of Research at the Research Institute of Geodesy and Cartography in Bratislava and is the Phare sector co-ordinator for Cadastre and Land Registration in the Slovak Republic. He is a delegate to FIG, and responsible for the co-ordination of all foreign assistance within the Authority.
Dr V. Voltr (Czech Republic). Dr Voltr is a researcher at the Research Institute of Agricultural Economics, Department of Agricultural Economy and is a specialist in land valuation for tax and subsidy purposes. He has published extensively.
Dr A. Zichy ( Austria). Dr Zichy is an economist who is currently the Policy Adviser to the Ministry of Agriculture in Slovenia. He has extensive international experience through UN FAO and is a former Senior Adviser to the Ministry of Agriculture Phare AICU in Hungary.
Ms B. Ziemele (Latvia). Ms Ziemele is a specialist in land registration who is active within the EU land registration project in Latvia. She is a member of several international societies.
Professor S. Zrobek (Poland). Professor Zrobek is a member of the Faculty of Geodesy and Regional Planning, Olsztyn University of Agriculture and Technology and has research interests in land registration, appraisal methods, valuation of urban land and properties, rational use of land at borders of towns, design of the system of mass appraisal for taxation purposes. She is a member of several Polish and International organisations.
The following tables show the results of the study as identified during 1997. Each of the case studies is documented fully within the ACE report (Project P2128R: The development of land markets in central and eastern Europe, ACE programme, final report 1998). The following summaries, together with Tables B1 - B6, provide a very brief assessment of the main findings.
The Czech Republic is hampered in its development by four main factors. Firstly, there are the potential claims of the exiled Sudetenland Germans. Secondly, the agricultural land market faces high transaction costs creating effective barriers through the lack of effective land units and the loss of the boundary data. Thirdly, the national agricultural policy is not conducive to investment in this sector. Lastly, the lack of financial regulation has resulted in various banking and investment funding scandals that have significantly reduced investment into the country. The institutional reforms have proceeded well in the land registration and cadastral sector but land valuation remains to be sorted out and an institutional framework with accurate and complete valuation information must be created. The financial pillar is handicapped by the poor financial regulation, but this is a priority problem for the government; significant progress should be expected over the next 2 or 3 years. The land market is still not yet robust.
Hungary has virtually completed all of the land related transition activities and by passing through the compensation programme, it has satisfied all outstanding land claims and there is no substantial group pressing for further land claims. It is also at the end of the three-year moratorium on land sales, following the compensation programme and it is reported that agricultural land has increased in average sale price by 500% in the last year. Land Consolidation is now proceeding and is taking place both through a government-backed programme and through voluntary sale and exchange. The compensation programme created a large number of players who now have a chance to share in the increase of the capital value of the property. The agriculture produce sector has also been largely restructured and there is a willingness to invest in this sector. Hungary seems to have managed this process with relatively little institutional reform in the land registration and cadastral sector. It could be that some reform would become necessary as the market increases and the demand for services widens, especially concerned with valuation. The financial pillar can be expected to grow significantly in the next 2 or 3 year period. The conclusion is that the land market is beginning to work in Hungary and the country is firmly in a market driven phase.
The Latvian land market is developing in and around Riga but elsewhere, especially in the rural areas, the market price for land is still very low. Agricultural land that has been restituted is, in many cases, reverting to scrub or forest because the owners are unwilling to sell until the prices rise. Sensitivities over the status of long-term residents of Russian origin inhibit a more open debate about land related issues. Awareness of land values is growing, partly as a result of the mass appraisal that has placed a market price on the land. When property-based taxes are introduced in the year 2000 this awareness will increase further.
The Polish land market is likewise hampered by the potential claims of groups who were expelled and who wish to recover their families property. Consequently there has been no formal restitution or compensation law enacted. Large amounts of land (more than 4 million hectares) are still held by the state through its holding company and this is a significant damper on the market and can potentially overshadow private sector activity. This is having a depressing influence on land prices. The institutional structures in Poland are still confused and there is no single national land administration authority as the responsibilities are split between different ministries and there has been interminable discussion about the future of the institutional structure. The administration is through the Voivods and consequently there is a structural weakness that affects further progress. The valuation system in Poland appears to be more advanced than in any of the other study countries but the land market is not yet working effectively.
Slovakia is handicapped in its land market by the difficulties arising from the lack of updating during the socialist years, resulting in large numbers of unknown owners as well as the loss of boundary information (as in the Czech Republic). There is still a significant amount of land held by the state land fund and the restitution is still only two thirds completed. It therefore suffers from structural problems arising directly from the socialist legacy. A further complication (as in the Czech Republic) is the potential claims of evicted landholders who were expelled after the end of the Second World War. The regulatory authorities are also weak in that the land registration and cadastre sector is operated as part of the overall state administration and consequently there is a loss of executive control. Valuation and Financial services are still underdeveloped and there are weak information flows. In order for the land market to begin to function, the owners and parcel data must be completed as a priority to complete the first stage transition. The institutional position of the regulating authorities also needs to be considered and the technical infrastructure is not yet in place.
The Slovenian land market is noticeably less active then the other case study countries. It is too early to assess the impact of the liberalisation of the market (it was supposedly opened to EU nationals in 1997) and this will only become clear over the next year or two. At the present time, the market suffers from a lack of technical infrastructure within the land registry. There is no large restitution programme and there are no significant potential outstanding claims. The same families have been settled on the land for generations in small plots and these are not often offered for sale. While people like to be associated with the land, they are not so interested in the active use. The second and third pillars follow the same pattern as the other countries, though financial services have been even slower to develop in Slovenia, as the general economy has remained more closed to outside companies. The chief impediments are considered to be the lack of technical infrastructure and lack of reliable information services from the Land Registry.
The overall assessment shows that in general, the reforms and institution building within the land registration sector (pillar one) have been more effective than the reforms in the valuation and financial services sector. There is a recognised weakness in policy formulation and coordinated institutional activities and a weakness in the establishment of a sufficient number and variety of participants in the land market itself, though Hungary has been noticeably successful in this area.
Table B1. Land Policy Framework Matrix Czech Republic
LAND POLICY FRAMEWORK MATRIX for Czech Republic |
|||||||
COMMAND ECONOMY ------->I<-----------TRANSITION ECONOMY----------------->I<-----MARKET ECONOMY------> |----- EU------ |
|||||||
LMI score
|
<1.5 |
1.5-1.90 |
2.0-2.4 |
2.5-2.9 |
3.0-3.4 |
3.5-3.9 |
>4.0 |
Policy Level Framework |
Government does not support land market development or individual property rights |
Weak political support for objectives of land market. No broad political consensus. |
Inconsistent or inadequate policies leading to fragmented land management. |
Individual policies sound. Some policy difficulties with coordination & information exchange. |
Policies are coherent and preparations have started for EU accession. |
All reforms are complete and negotiations for accession are under way. |
Clearly defined and integrated land policies that comply with EU regulations. |
Market Assessment – Participants |
Relationship between land and people is weak with focus on use rights and occupancy, not ownership. Strong informal sector. Poor information |
Participation severely restricted with unclear ownership rights and outstanding legal claims. Identification of owners and parcels difficult |
Participation starting but interest limited due to structural problems and lack of market confidence. Data flows are weak. |
Relationship between land and people becoming clear. Growing interest in land as a market commodity. Data flows improving. |
Strong connection between land and people with a range of participants and types of land for sale. Information flows are working. |
Institutional investors and investment funds are active in the market. Risks in real estate investment seen as low. Information is transparent |
Large range of participants, goods and services. Real estate seen as a good, safe long-term investment. |
Pillar One – Land Registration and Cadastre |
Registration not legally required. Insecure laws with respect to ownership, inheritance and disposal of rights. Weak regulating authorities. |
Registration is legally required but there are inconsistent laws and confusion over administrative responsibility between agencies. |
Compilation of registers and land reform under way. Institutional arrangements and land law need to be strengthened. Poor title information. |
Requirements for land title registration are basically satisfactory but delays in transactions occur due to technical and organisation problems. |
Land Registration System is basically working Problems with titling are mainly in large cities and in areas under land reform. |
Records near completion. System working efficiently (except in capital cities). Titles are secure. Land reform is complete. |
System is efficient and supports secondary market services, significant private sector involvement & cost recovery. |
Pillar Two - Valuation |
Absence of any accepted methodology for market based valuations. No body tasked with valuation. |
There is a valuation methodology but little up to date or reliable data. Valuation may not be connected to market price. |
Valuations tied to market price but results are unreliable due to poor data, low level of transactions, and poor reporting. |
Systematic valuation records being compiled. Valuation seen as necessary to support the land market. Real Estate prices volatile. |
Valuation system able to support market based property tax. Regulatory procedures are in place to monitor data quality . |
Secure, reliable system supporting land transactions and fair and efficient property tax collection. |
Complete valuation data sets available that can link to other land administration records. Significant private sector involvement. |
Pillar Three -Financial Services |
Almost complete absence of financing mechanisms. |
Cash sales take place but the market is volatile with few transactions and potential speculation. |
Mortgage support being introduced but foreign investment into real estate may be restricted. |
Mortgages have become more accepted, and development financing is emerging. |
Mortgages more widely available, interest rates near to EU/G7 norm . |
Macro-economic stability helps real estate investment, encouraging institutional investors. |
Pension funds, investment funds, life assurance and major investors are in place and safe |
General Assessment |
Land market operates through informal sector outside government authority. |
Severe strategic impediments to land market activity with reforms progressing very slowly. |
Major impediments to a formal land market. Reforms in progress but there are major policy weaknesses. |
Reforms are being implemented but with unresolved difficulties that inhibit development. |
System is basically working and land rights are seen as secure and transferable. |
A mature market is beginning to appear with transparent land dealings. |
Stable and secure real estate market, secondary market services developed. |
Table B2. Land Policy Framework Matrix for Hungary
LAND POLICY FRAMEWORK MATRIX for Hungary |
|||||||
COMMAND ECONOMY -------->I<---------------TRANSITION ECONOMY--------------->Iß -----MARKET ECONOMY----> |----- EU------ |
|||||||
LMI score
|
<1.5 |
1.5-1.90 |
2.0-2.4 |
2.5-2.9 |
3.0-3.4 |
3.5-3.9 |
>4.0 |
Policy Level Framework |
Government does not support land market development or individual property rights |
Weak political support for objectives of land market. No broad political consensus. |
Inconsistent or inadequate policies leading to fragmented land management. |
Individual policies sound. Some policy difficulties with coordination & information exchange. |
Policies are coherent and preparations have started for EU accession. |
All reforms are complete and negotiations for accession are under way. |
Clearly defined and integrated land policies that comply with EU regulations. |
Market Assessment – Participants |
Relationship between land and people is weak with Focus on use rights and occupancy, not ownership. Strong informal sector. Poor information |
Participation severely restricted with unclear ownership rights and outstanding legal claims. Identification of owners and parcels difficult |
Participation starting but interest limited due to structural problems and lack of market confidence. Data flows are weak. |
Relationship between land and people becoming clear. Growing interest in land as a market commodity. Data flows improving. |
Strong connection between land and people with a range of participants and types of land for sale. Information flows are working. |
Institutional investors and investment funds are active in the market. Risks in real estate investment seen as low. Information is transparent |
Large range of participants, goods and services. Real estate seen as a good, safe long-term investment. |
Pillar One – Land Registration and Cadastre |
Registration not legally required. Insecure laws with respect to ownership, inheritance and disposal of rights. Weak regulating authorities. |
Registration is legally required but there are inconsistent laws and confusion over administrative responsibility between agencies. |
Compilation of registers and land reform under way. Institutional arrangements and land law need to be strengthened. Poor title information. |
Requirements for land title registration are basically satisfactory but delays in transactions occur due to technical and organisation problems. |
Land Registration System is basically working Problems with titling are mainly in large cities and in areas under land reform. |
Records near completion. System working efficiently (except in capital cities). Titles are secure. Land reform is complete. |
System is efficient and supports secondary market services, significant private sector involvement & cost recovery. |
Pillar Two - Valuation |
Absence of any accepted methodology for market based valuations. No body tasked with valuation. |
There is a valuation methodology but little up to date or reliable data. Valuation may not be connected to market price. |
Valuations tied to market price but results are unreliable due to poor data, low level of transactions, and poor reporting. |
Systematic valuation records being compiled. Valuation seen as necessary to support the land market. Real Estate prices volatile. |
Valuation system able to support market based property tax. Regulatory procedures are in place to monitor data quality . |
Secure, reliable system supporting land transactions and fair and efficient property tax collection. |
Complete valuation data sets available that can link to other land administration records. Significant private sector involvement. |
Pillar Three -Financial Services |
Almost complete absence of financing mechanisms. |
Cash sales take place but the market is volatile with few transactions and potential speculation. |
Mortgage support being introduced but foreign investment into real estate may be restricted. |
Mortgages have become more accepted, and development financing is emerging. |
Mortgages more widely available, interest rates near to EU/G7 norm . |
Macro-economic stability helps real estate investment, encouraging institutional investors. |
Pension funds, investment funds, life assurance and major investors are in place and safe |
General Assessment |
Land market operates through informal sector outside government authority. |
Severe strategic impediments to land market activity with reforms progressing very slowly. |
Major impediments to a formal land market. Reforms in progress but there are major policy weaknesses. |
Reforms are being implemented but with unresolved difficulties that inhibit development. |
System is basically working and land rights are seen as secure and transferable. |
A mature market is beginning to appear with transparent land dealings. |
Stable and secure real estate market, secondary market services developed. |
Table B3. Land Policy Framework Matrix for Latvia
LAND POLICY FRAMEWORK MATRIX for Latvia |
|||||||
COMMAND ECONOMY ------>Iß ------------TRANSITION ECONOMY--------------->Iß -----MARKET ECONOMY-------> |----- EU------ |
|||||||
LMI score
|
<1.5 |
1.5-1.90 |
2.0-2.4 |
2.5-2.9 |
3.0-3.4 |
3.5-3.9 |
>4.0 |
Policy Level Framework |
Government does not support land market development or individual property rights |
Weak political support for objectives of land market. No broad political consensus. |
Inconsistent or inadequate policies leading to fragmented land management. |
Individual policies sound. Some policy difficulties with coordination & information exchange. |
Policies are coherent and preparations have started for EU accession. |
All reforms are complete and negotiations for accession are under way. |
Clearly defined and integrated land policies that comply with EU regulations. |
Market Assessment – Participants |
Relationship between land and people is weak with focus on use rights and occupancy, not ownership. Strong informal sector. Poor information |
Participation severely restricted with unclear ownership rights and outstanding legal claims. Identification of owners and parcels difficult |
Participation starting but interest limited due to structural problems and lack of market confidence. Data flows are weak. |
Relationship between land and people becoming clear. Growing interest in land as a market commodity. Data flows improving. |
Strong connection between land and people with a range of participants and types of land for sale. Information flows are working. |
Institutional investors and investment funds are active in the market. Risks in real estate investment seen as low. Information is transparent |
Large range of participants, goods and services. Real estate seen as a good, safe long-term investment. |
Pillar One – Land Registration and Cadastre |
Registration not legally required. Insecure laws with respect to ownership, inheritance and disposal of rights. Weak regulating authorities. |
Registration is legally required but there are inconsistent laws and confusion over administrative responsibility between agencies. |
Compilation of registers and land reform under way. Institutional arrangements and land law need to be strengthened. Poor title information. |
Requirements for land title registration are basically satisfactory but delays in transactions occur due to technical and organisation problems. |
Land Registration System is basically working Problems with titling are mainly in large cities and in areas under land reform. |
Records near completion. System working efficiently (except in capital cities). Titles are secure. Land reform is complete. |
System is efficient and supports secondary market services, significant private sector involvement & cost recovery. |
Pillar Two - Valuation |
Absence of any accepted methodology for market based valuations. No body tasked with valuation. |
There is a valuation methodology but little up to date or reliable data. Valuation may not be connected to market price. |
Valuations tied to market price but results are unreliable due to poor data, low level of transactions, and poor reporting. |
Systematic valuation records being compiled. Valuation seen as necessary to support the land market. Real Estate prices volatile. |
Valuation system able to support market based property tax. Regulatory procedures are in place to monitor data quality . |
Secure, reliable system supporting land transactions and fair and efficient property tax collection. |
Complete valuation data sets available that can link to other land administration records. Significant private sector involvement. |
Pillar Three -Financial Services |
Almost complete absence of financing mechanisms. |
Cash sales take place but the market is volatile with few transactions and potential speculation. |
Mortgage support being introduced but foreign investment into real estate may be restricted. |
Mortgages have become more accepted, and development financing is emerging. |
Mortgages more widely available, interest rates near to EU/G7 norm . |
Macro-economic stability helps real estate investment, encouraging institutional investors. |
Pension funds, investment funds, life assurance and major investors are in place and safe |
General Assessment |
Land market operates through informal sector outside government authority. |
Severe strategic impediments to land market activity with reforms progressing very slowly. |
Major impediments to a formal land market. Reforms in progress but there are major policy weaknesses. |
Reforms are being implemented but with unresolved difficulties that inhibit development. |
System is basically working and land rights are seen as secure and transferable. |
A mature market is beginning to appear with transparent land dealings. |
Stable and secure real estate market, secondary market services developed. |
Table 4. Land Policy Framework Matrix for Poland
LAND POLICY FRAMEWORK MATRIX for Poland |
|||||||
COMMAND ECONOMY ------->I<---------------TRANSITION ECONOMY-------------->Iß ------MARKET ECONOMY-----> |----- EU------ |
|||||||
LMI score
|
<1.5 |
1.5-1.90 |
2.0-2.4 |
2.5-2.9 |
3.0-3.4 |
3.5-3.9 |
>4.0 |
Policy Level Framework |
Government does not support land market development or individual property rights |
Weak political support for objectives of land market. No broad political consensus. |
Inconsistent or inadequate policies leading to fragmented land management. |
Individual policies sound. Some policy difficulties with coordination & information exchange. |
Policies are coherent and preparations have started for EU accession. |
All reforms are complete and negotiations for accession are under way. |
Clearly defined and integrated land policies that comply with EU regulations. |
Market Assessment – Participants |
Relationship between land and people is weak with focus on use rights and occupancy, not ownership. Strong informal sector. Poor information |
Participation severely restricted with unclear ownership rights and outstanding legal claims. Identification of owners and parcels difficult |
Participation starting but interest limited due to structural problems and lack of market confidence. Data flows are weak. |
Relationship between land and people becoming clear. Growing interest in land as a market commodity. Data flows improving. |
Strong connection between land and people with a range of participants and types of land for sale. Information flows are working. |
Institutional investors and investment funds are active in the market. Risks in real estate investment seen as low. Information is transparent |
Large range of participants, goods and services. Real estate seen as a good, safe long-term investment. |
Pillar One – Land Registration and Cadastre |
Registration not legally required. Insecure laws with respect to ownership, inheritance and disposal of rights. Weak regulating authorities. |
Registration is legally required but there are inconsistent laws and confusion over administrative responsibility between agencies. |
Compilation of registers and land reform under way. Institutional arrangements and land law need to be strengthened. Poor title information. |
Requirements for land title registration are basically satisfactory but delays in transactions occur due to technical and organisation problems. |
Land Registration System is basically working Problems with titling are mainly in large cities and in areas under land reform. |
Records near completion. System working efficiently (except in capital cities). Titles are secure. Land reform is complete. |
System is efficient and supports secondary market services, significant private sector involvement & cost recovery. |
Pillar Two - Valuation |
Absence of any accepted methodology for market based valuations. No body tasked with valuation. |
There is a valuation methodology but little up to date or reliable data. Valuation may not be connected to market price. |
Valuations tied to market price but results are unreliable due to poor data, low level of transactions, and poor reporting. |
Systematic valuation records being compiled. Valuation seen as necessary to support the land market. Real Estate prices volatile. |
Valuation system able to support market based property tax. Regulatory procedures are in place to monitor data quality . |
Secure, reliable system supporting land transactions and fair and efficient property tax collection. |
Complete valuation data sets available that can link to other land administration records. Significant private sector involvement. |
Pillar Three -Financial Services |
Almost complete absence of financing mechanisms. |
Cash sales take place but the market is volatile with few transactions and potential speculation. |
Mortgage support being introduced but foreign investment into real estate may be restricted. |
Mortgages have become more accepted, and development financing is emerging. |
Mortgages more widely available, interest rates near to EU/G7 norm . |
Macro-economic stability helps real estate investment, encouraging institutional investors. |
Pension funds, investment funds, life assurance and major investors are in place and safe |
General Assessment |
Land market operates through informal sector outside government authority. |
Severe strategic impediments to land market activity with reforms progressing very slowly. |
Major impediments to a formal land market. Reforms in progress but there are major policy weaknesses. |
Reforms are being implemented but with unresolved difficulties that inhibit development. |
System is basically working and land rights are seen as secure and transferable. |
A mature market is beginning to appear with transparent land dealings. |
Stable and secure real estate market, secondary market services developed. |
Table 5. Land Policy Framework Matrix for Slovakia
LAND POLICY FRAMEWORK MATRIX for Slovakia |
|||||||
COMMAND ECONOMY -------->I<--------------TRANSITION ECONOMY--------------->I<------MARKET ECONOMY-----> |----- EU------ |
|||||||
LMI score
|
<1.5 |
1.5-1.90 |
2.0-2.4 |
2.5-2.9 |
3.0-3.4 |
3.5-3.9 |
>4.0 |
Policy Level Framework |
Government does not support land market development or individual property rights |
Weak political support for objectives of land market. No broad political consensus. |
Inconsistent or inadequate policies leading to fragmented land management. |
Individual policies sound. Some policy difficulties with coordination & information exchange. |
Policies are coherent and preparations have started for EU accession. |
All reforms are complete and negotiations for accession are under way. |
Clearly defined and integrated land policies that comply with EU regulations. |
Market Assessment – Participants |
Relationship between land and people is weak with focus on use rights and occupancy, not ownership. Strong informal sector. Poor information |
Participation severely restricted with unclear ownership rights and outstanding legal claims. Identification of owners and parcels difficult |
Participation starting but interest limited due to structural problems and lack of market confidence. Data flows are weak. |
Relationship between land and people becoming clear. Growing interest in land as a market commodity. Data flows improving. |
Strong connection between land and people with a range of participants and types of land for sale. Information flows are working. |
Institutional investors and investment funds are active in the market. Risks in real estate investment seen as low. Information is transparent |
Large range of participants, goods and services. Real estate seen as a good, safe long-term investment. |
Pillar One – Land Registration and Cadastre |
Registration not legally required. Insecure laws with respect to ownership, inheritance and disposal of rights. Weak regulating authorities. |
Registration is legally required but there are inconsistent laws and confusion over administrative responsibility between agencies. |
Compilation of registers and land reform under way. Institutional arrangements and land law need to be strengthened. Poor title information. |
Requirements for land title registration are basically satisfactory but delays in transactions occur due to technical and organisation problems. |
Land Registration System is basically working Problems with titling are mainly in large cities and in areas under land reform. |
Records near completion. System working efficiently (except in capital cities). Titles are secure. Land reform is complete. |
System is efficient and supports secondary market services, significant private sector involvement & cost recovery. |
Pillar Two - Valuation |
Absence of any accepted methodology for market based valuations. No body tasked with valuation. |
There is a valuation methodology but little up to date or reliable data. Valuation may not be connected to market price. |
Valuations tied to market price but results are unreliable due to poor data, low level of transactions, and poor reporting. |
Systematic valuation records being compiled. Valuation seen as necessary to support the land market. Real Estate prices volatile. |
Valuation system able to support market based property tax. Regulatory procedures are in place to monitor data quality . |
Secure, reliable system supporting land transactions and fair and efficient property tax collection. |
Complete valuation data sets available that can link to other land administration records. Significant private sector involvement. |
Pillar Three -Financial Services |
Almost complete absence of financing mechanisms. |
Cash sales take place but the market is volatile with few transactions and potential speculation. |
Mortgage support being introduced but foreign investment into real estate may be restricted. |
Mortgages have become more accepted, and development financing is emerging. |
Mortgages more widely available, interest rates near to EU/G7 norm . |
Macro-economic stability helps real estate investment, encouraging institutional investors. |
Pension funds, investment funds, life assurance and major investors are in place and safe |
General Assessment |
Land market operates through informal sector outside government authority. |
Severe strategic impediments to land market activity with reforms progressing very slowly. |
Major impediments to a formal land market. Reforms in progress but there are major policy weaknesses. |
Reforms are being implemented but with unresolved difficulties that inhibit development. |
System is basically working and land rights are seen as secure and transferable. |
A mature market is beginning to appear with transparent land dealings. |
Stable and secure real estate market, secondary market services developed. |
Table B6. Land Policy Framework Matrix for Slovenia
LAND POLICY FRAMEWORK MATRIX for Slovenia |
|||||||
COMMAND ECONOMY ------->I<---------------TRANSITION ECONOMY--------------->I<------MARKET ECONOMY-----> |----- EU------ |
|||||||
LMI score
|
<1.5 |
1.5-1.90 |
2.0-2.4 |
2.5-2.9 |
3.0-3.4 |
3.5-3.9 |
>4.0 |
Policy Level Framework |
Government does not support land market development or individual property rights |
Weak political support for objectives of land market. No broad political consensus. |
Inconsistent or inadequate policies leading to fragmented land management. |
Individual policies sound. Some policy difficulties with coordination & information exchange. |
Policies are coherent and preparations have started for EU accession. |
All reforms are complete and negotiations for accession are under way. |
Clearly defined and integrated land policies that comply with EU regulations. |
Market Assessment – Participants |
Relationship between land and people is weak with focus on use rights and occupancy, not ownership. Strong informal sector. Poor information |
Participation severely restricted with unclear ownership rights and outstanding legal claims. Identification of owners and parcels difficult |
Participation starting but interest limited due to structural problems and lack of market confidence. Data flows are weak. |
Relationship between land and people becoming clear. Growing interest in land as a market commodity. Data flows improving. |
Strong connection between land and people with a range of participants and types of land for sale. Information flows are working. |
Institutional investors and investment funds are active in the market. Risks in real estate investment seen as low. Information is transparent |
Large range of participants, goods and services. Real estate seen as a good, safe long-term investment. |
Pillar One – Land Registration and Cadastre |
Registration not legally required. Insecure laws with respect to ownership, inheritance and disposal of rights. Weak regulating authorities. |
Registration is legally required but there are inconsistent laws and confusion over administrative responsibility between agencies. |
Compilation of registers and land reform under way. Institutional arrangements and land law need to be strengthened. Poor title information. |
Requirements for land title registration are basically satisfactory but delays in transactions occur due to technical and organisation problems. |
Land Registration System is basically working Problems with titling are mainly in large cities and in areas under land reform. |
Records near completion. System working efficiently (except in capital cities). Titles are secure. Land reform is complete. |
System is efficient and supports secondary market services, significant private sector involvement & cost recovery. |
Pillar Two - Valuation |
Absence of any accepted methodology for market based valuations. No body tasked with valuation. |
There is a valuation methodology but little up to date or reliable data. Valuation may not be connected to market price. |
Valuations tied to market price but results are unreliable due to poor data, low level of transactions, and poor reporting. |
Systematic valuation records being compiled. Valuation seen as necessary to support the land market. Real Estate prices volatile. |
Valuation system able to support market based property tax. Regulatory procedures are in place to monitor data quality . |
Secure, reliable system supporting land transactions and fair and efficient property tax collection. |
Complete valuation data sets available that can link to other land administration records. Significant private sector involvement. |
Pillar Three -Financial Services |
Almost complete absence of financing mechanisms. |
Cash sales take place but the market is volatile with few transactions and potential speculation. |
Mortgage support being introduced but foreign investment into real estate may be restricted. |
Mortgages have become more accepted, and development financing is emerging. |
Mortgages more widely available, interest rates near to EU/G7 norm . |
Macro-economic stability helps real estate investment, encouraging institutional investors. |
Pension funds, investment funds, life assurance and major investors are in place and safe |
General Assessment |
Land market operates through informal sector outside government authority. |
Severe strategic impediments to land market activity with reforms progressing very slowly. |
Major impediments to a formal land market. Reforms in progress but there are major policy weaknesses. |
Reforms are being implemented but with unresolved difficulties that inhibit development. |
System is basically working and land rights are seen as secure and transferable. |
A mature market is beginning to appear with transparent land dealings. |
Stable and secure real estate market, secondary market services developed. |
Dr R. Baldwin (UK). Project Coordinator. Dr Baldwin is a consultant who is active in the land registration and cadastre sector. He has spent six years working on land registration projects in Hungary, Czech Republic, Lebanon and shorter assignments in Slovenia and Slovakia and other countries. Currently he is the GIS/LIS Projects Director for Central and Eastern Europe, BlomInfo A/S.
Professor P. Dale (UK). Professor Dale is President of FIG and is based at University College London. He was the Chairman of the UN ECE Land Administration Guidelines Taskforce, and has carried out consultancy in central and eastern Europe and many other countries on behalf of the EU Phare programme and the World Bank. He is the author of several books and more than 100 papers.
Professor Peter Dale
University College London
E-mail: pdale@ge.ucl.ac.uk
Dr. Richard Baldwin
GIS/LIS Projects Director
BlomInfo A/S
E-mail: Richarolin@aol.com
19 April 2000